Property Rights, Externalities, and Natural Resource Problems
September 6, 2024
Over half of 1100 hectares of mangrove swamps cleared for commercial shrimp farms in Tha Po village, Surat Thani Province, Thailand.
Consequences of mangrove destruction:
Problem: Shrimp farmers, due to subsidies and not bearing external costs, are incentivized to convert mangroves
Conclusion: Without regulation or collective action, conversion to shrimp farming will continue despite being socially inefficient
Communities in Thailand are restoring degraded mangrove forests to grow and harvest clean, healthy shrimp. (National Geographic, 2016)
Private property is not the only regime of defining entitlements to resource use.
Res nullius property resources, or open-access resources by definition do not have a process for controlling access to this resource, because no individual or group has the legal power exercise that control.
Open-access resources have given rise to what has become known popularly as the “tragedy of the commons”.
Bison are an example of “open-access, common-pool” resources.
Common-pool resources are non-excludible and rivalrous.
Northern and Southern Herd of Bison in 1865
Surplus is measured as benefits (or revenues) received from the harvest minus costs.
Total benefit is calculated by multiplying the price per bison by the number of bison harvested at each level of hunting.
The upward-sloping total cost curve reflects the fact that increases in harvest effort result in higher total costs.
In the presence of sufficient demand, unrestricted access will cause resources to be overexploited
The surplus is dissipated—no one is able to appropriate it, so it is lost.
Unlimited access destroys the incentive to conserve.